Al-Jazeerah: Cross-Cultural Understanding
www.ccun.org www.aljazeerah.info |
Opinion Editorials, February 2014 |
||||||||||||||||||
Archives Mission & Name Conflict Terminology Editorials Gaza Holocaust Gulf War Isdood Islam News News Photos Opinion Editorials US Foreign Policy (Dr. El-Najjar's Articles) www.aljazeerah.info
|
Usurious Returns on Phantom Money: The Credit Card Gravy Train By Ellen Brown Al-Jazeerah, CCUN, February 24, 2014
The credit card business is now the banking industry’s biggest cash cow, and
it’s largely due to lucrative hidden fees. You pay off your credit card balance every month,
thinking you are taking advantage of the “interest-free grace period” and
getting free credit. You may even use your credit card when you could have
used cash, just to get the free frequent flier or cash-back rewards. But
those popular features are misleading. Even when the balance is paid on time
every month, credit card use imposes a huge hidden cost on users—hidden
because the cost is deducted from what the merchant receives, then passed on
to you in the form of higher prices.
Visa and MasterCard charge merchants about 2% of the value of every
credit card transaction, and American Express charges even more. That may
not sound like much. But consider that for balances that are paid off
monthly (meaning most of them), the banks make 2% or more on a loan
averaging only about 25 days (depending on when in the month the charge was
made and when in the grace period it was paid).
Two percent interest for 25 days works out
to a 33.5% return annually (1.02^(365/25) – 1), and that figure may be
conservative. Merchant fees were originally designed as a way
to avoid usury and
Truth-in-Lending laws. Visa and MasterCard are independent entities, but
they were set up by big Wall Street banks, and the card-issuing banks get
about 80% of the fees. The annual returns not only fall in the usurious
category, but they are
returns on other people’s
money – usually the borrower’s own money! Here
is how it works . . . .
The Ultimate Shell Game Economist Hyman Minsky observed that anyone can
create money; the trick is to get it accepted. The function of the credit
card company is to turn your IOU, or promise to pay, into a “negotiable
instrument” acceptable in the payment of debt. A negotiable instrument is
anything that is signed and convertible into money or that can be used as
money.
Under Article 9 of the Uniform Commercial Code,
when you sign the merchant’s credit card charge receipt, you are creating a
“negotiable instrument or other writing which evidences a right to the
payment of money.” This negotiable instrument is deposited electronically
into the merchant’s checking account, a special account required of all
businesses that accept credit.
The account goes up by the amount on the receipt, indicating that the
merchant has been paid. The
charge receipt is forwarded to an “acquiring settlement bank,” which bundles
your charges and sends them to your own bank. Your bank then sends you a
statement and you pay the balance with a check, causing your transaction
account to be debited at your bank.
The net effect is that your charge receipt (a negotiable instrument) has
become an “asset” against which credit has been advanced.
The bank has simply monetized your IOU, turning it into money.
The credit cycle is so short that this process can occur without the
bank’s own money even being involved.
Debits and credits are just shuffled back and forth between accounts.
Timothy Madden is a Canadian financial analyst who built software models of
credit card accounts in the early 1990s. In personal correspondence, he
estimates that payouts from the bank’s own reserves are necessary only about
2% of the time; and the 2% merchant’s fee is sufficient to cover these
occasions. The “reserves” necessary to back the short-term advances are thus
built into the payments themselves, without drawing from anywhere else.
As for the interest,
Madden maintains:
The interest is all gravy because the transactions are funded in fact
by the signed payment voucher issued by the card-user at the point of
purchase. Assume that the monthly gross sales that are run through
credit/charge-cards globally double, from the normal $300 billion to $600
billion for the year-end holiday period. The card companies do not have to
worry about where the extra $300 billion will come from because it is
provided by the additional $300 billion of signed vouchers themselves. . . .
That is also why virtually all banks everywhere
have to write-off 100% of credit/charge-card accounts in arrears for
180 days. The basic design of the system recognizes that, once set in
motion, the system is entirely self-financing requiring zero equity
investment by the operator . . . . The losses cannot be charged off against
the operator's equity because they don't have any. In the early 1990's when
I was building computer/software models of the credit/charge-card system, my
spreadsheets kept "blowing up" because of "divide by zero" errors in my
return-on-equity display.
A Private
Sales Tax All this sheds light on why the credit card business
has become the most lucrative pursuit of the banking industry. At one time,
banking was all about taking deposits and making commercial and residential
loans. But in recent years,
according to the Federal Reserve, “credit card earnings have been almost
always higher than returns on all commercial bank activities.” Partly, this is because the interest charged on
credit card debt is higher than on other commercial loans. But it is on the
fees that the banks really make their money. There are late payment fees,
fees for exceeding the credit limit, balance transfer fees, cash withdrawal
fees, and annual fees, in addition to the very lucrative merchant fees that
accrue at the point of sale whether the customer pays his bill or not. The
merchant absorbs the fees, and the customers cover the cost with higher
prices.
A 2%
merchants’ fee is the financial equivalent of a 2% sales tax
– one that now adds up to
over $30 billion
annually in the US. The effect on trade is worse than either a public
sales tax or a financial transaction tax (or Tobin tax), since these taxes
are designed to be spent back into the economy on
services and infrastructure. A private merchant’s tax simply removes
purchasing power from the economy.
As financial blogger Yves Smith observes:
[W]hen anyone brings up Tobin taxes (small charges on
every [financial] trade) as a way to pay for the bailout and discourage
speculation, the financial services industry becomes utterly apoplectic. . .
. Yet here in our very midst, we have a Tobin tax equivalent on a very high
proportion of retail trade. . . . [Y]ou can think of the rapacious Visa and
Mastercharge charges for debit transactions . . . as having two components:
the fee they’d be able to charge if they faced some competition, and the
premium they extract by controlling the market and refusing to compete on
price. In terms of its effect on commerce, this premium is worse than a
Tobin tax. A Tobin tax is intended to have the positive effect
of dampening speculation. A private tax on retail sales has the negative
effect of dampening consumer trade. It is a self-destruct mechanism that
consumes capital and credit at every turn of the credit cycle. The lucrative credit card business is a major factor
in
the increasing “financialization” of the economy. Companies
like General Electric are largely abandoning product innovation and becoming
credit card companies, because that’s where the money is.
Financialization is killing the economy, productivity, innovation, and
consumer demand.
Busting the Monopoly Exorbitant merchant fees are made possible because
the market is monopolized by a tiny number of credit card companies, and
entry into the market is difficult. To participate, you need to be part of a
network, and the network requires that all participating banks charge a
pre-set fee. The rules vary, however, by country. An option
available in some countries is to provide cheaper credit card services
through publicly-owned banks. In Costa Rica, 80% of deposits are held in
four publicly-owned banks; and all offer Visa/MC debit cards and will take
Visa/MC credit cards. Businesses that choose to affiliate with the two
largest public banks pay no transaction fees for that bank’s cards, and for
the cards of other banks they pay only a tiny fee, sufficient to cover the
bank’s costs. That works in Costa Rica; but in the US, Visa/MC fees
are pre-set, and public banks would have to charge that fee to participate
in the system. There is another way, however, that they could recapture the
merchant fees and use them for the benefit of the people: by returning them
in the form of lower taxes or increased public services. Local governments pay hefty fees for credit card use
themselves. According to the treasurer’s office, the City and County of San
Francisco pay $4 million annually just for bank fees, and more than half
this sum goes to merchant fees. If the government could recapture these
charges through its own bank, it could use the proceeds to expand public
services without raising taxes. If we allowed government to actually make some money,
it could be self-funding without taxing the citizens. When an alternative
public system is in place, the private mega-bank dinosaurs will no longer be
“too big to fail.” They can be allowed to fade into extinction, in a natural
process of evolution toward a more efficient and sustainable system of
exchange. ____________
Ellen Brown is an attorney, chairman of the Public
Banking Institute,
and author of twelve books including the bestselling
Web of Debt.
In her latest book, The
Public Bank Solution,
she explores successful public banking models historically and globally. She
is currently running for
California State Treasurer on a state bank platform. |
|
Opinions expressed in various sections are the sole responsibility of their authors and they may not represent Al-Jazeerah & ccun.org. editor@aljazeerah.info & editor@ccun.org |